- Details
- Category: Contract Law
- Hits: 16530
Historical development of contract law
This section provides a very brief account of the historical development of contract law. The historical development of contract law can be under stood in terms of the conceptual foundations of obligations, which was traced back to ancient and classical Roman law. However the foundations of the present day law of contract were laid in the 19th century. This period in history saw the rapid expansion of trade and industry inevitable resulting in the increments in the volume of commercial disputes as a result people turned to the court of law for solutions. Gradually, there developed a body of settled rules which reflected and of the disputes from which they arose and the prevailing belief of the time. However, this rules and belief are affected by the dominant economic philosophy, the so called the laissez-faire individualism-the view that the state should not meddle in the affairs of business and that individuals should be free to determine their own destinies. This philosophy was mirrored in the law of contract by two assumptions-freedom of contract and equality of bargaining power. According to freedom of contract theory it is assumed that everyone is free to choose which contracts they entered into and the terms on which they wish to do so. According to equality of bargaining power theory, the parties were deemed to have equal power to bargain on their business and deemed to be of equal bargaining strength.
These theoretical foundations of contract law produced an acceptable legal framework for the regulation of business transaction that resulted in the crystallization or codifications of contract laws across the world. The two theories did also define the role of the courts. Courts were required to enforce the agreement of the parties, as it was without questions its fairness etc. Over years the freedom of contract theory though maintained at present is subjected to different limitations. The theory of equality of bargaining power had brought certain unnecessary results because parties to a contract do not necessarily have equality. For example, employers and employees, producers and consumers, lenders and borrowers do not have equal power in the negotiations. Employees, for example, did not have equal bargaining power with employers, and as a result entered in to contracts the terms of which were more favorable to the employers (employees were supposed to work for as long as 16 hours per day & more, less wages etc). Courts were simply required to enforce such terms. This led to dissatisfaction, riots, unrest etc calling for government intervention. Thus, governments do lay down the minimum conditions for enforceable employment contracts. Today, we find the law of contract providing the conditions for the making and enforcement of contract. However, we should note that the theory of freedom of contract and equality of bargaining power are still the foundations of contract law in many legal systems.
The Economic Analysis of Contract Law
This section is intended to introduce an emerging discipline of law and economics as applied in contracts. The economic analysis of contract law provides a new paradigm into contract law in terms of both defining the concept and the economic function of contract & contract law. As the subject is vast to cover in this material, we have opted to consider some of the concepts and assumptions suggested by leading scholars (Look ‘Economics of Contract Law’ by Kronman and Posner (1979) for further understanding).
One fundamental economic principle is that if voluntary exchanges are permitted-if, in other words, a market is allowed to operate-resources will gravitate towards their most valuable uses. The exchange will make not only the parties better off but will also increases the wealth of the society, assuming that the exchange does not reduce the welfare of nonparties more than it increases the welfare of the parties. The existence of the market-locus of opportunities for mutually advantageous exchanges-facilitates the allocation of the good or service in question to the use in which it is most valuable, thereby maximizing the wealth of society.
It is assumed that individuals are rational maximizes of their own self-interests. That is, they will respond to other people and to events in a way that increases their own utility. It is this, which lies behind the notion that individuals will trade resources until the resources reach the people who value them most highly. Economists express the idea that something may be worth more to one person than to another by saying the first will be prepared to pay more for it than the second. However, they use the word “utility’ rather than ‘wealth’ because the theory does not assume that everyone is selfishly pursuing greater personal wealth. Individuals may well like to see other individuals made better off and be prepared to give some of their own wealth to achieve that. An economist fits this into his general theory by saying the donor’s ‘utility’ is increased by seeing the donee made better off.
The basic economic function of contract law is to provide sanction for reneging, which, is in the absence of sanctions, sometimes tempting where the parties’ performance is not simultaneous. During the process of an extended exchange, a point may be reached where it is in the interest (though perhaps short-run interest) of one of the parties to terminate performance. If A agrees to build a house for B and B pays him in advance, A can make himself better off, at least if loss of reputation (which, depending on A’s particular situation, may be unimportant to him) is ignored, by pocketing B’s money and not building the house. The problem arises because the non-simultaneous character of the exchange offers one of the parties a strategic advantage, which he can use to obtain a transfer payment that utterly vitiates the advantages of the contract to the other party. Clearly, if such conduct were permitted, people would be reluctant to enter into contracts and the process of economic exchange would be retarded. Hence, the basic function of contract law to provide a sanction for breach of promises.
A non instantaneous or extended exchange creates not only strategic opportunities that parties might try to exploit in the absence of legal sanction, but also uncertainty with regard to the conditions under which performance will occur. This uncertainty exposes the parties to the risk that the costs and benefits of their exchange will turn out to be different from what they expected. An important function of contract law in this regard is to enforce the parties’ agreed upon allocation of risk.
A related function is to reduce the costs of the exchange process by supplying a standard set of risk allocation terms for use by contracting parties. Many substantive rules of contract law are simply specifications of the consequences of some contingency for which the contract makes an express provision. If the parties are satisfied with the way in which the rules allocate the risk of that contingency, they have no need to incur the expense of writing their own risk allocation rule in to the contract.
- Details
- Category: Contract Law
- Hits: 32028
Though the questions ‘what is contract?’ and “what is contract law?” are of paramount importance, it is difficult to give a definitive answer to either. But one may say contract law is most obviously the law relating to agreements or promises. It is primarily concerned with agreements in which one party, or each party, gives an undertaking or promise to the other. It governs such questions as which agreements the law will enforce, what obligations are imposed by the agreement in question and what remedies are available if the obligations are not performed. Thus contract law is the law based on liability for breach of promises. However, ‘Contract law’ is also used to mean the whole collections of rules, which apply to contracts, and these includes many rules, which are not contractual in the sense of being based on a promise to do something. For example, if one party induces the other to enter a contract by fraud or misrepresentation, the innocent party may avail himself of certain remedies based on the rules of misrepresentation (fraud). There are certain conceptual differences on whether such rules are part of contract law or tort.
Contract law is primarily concerned with supporting the social institution of exchange. However, it is not as broad as the institution itself. An enormous proportion of our life is carried on the basis of exchanges that are in some sense agreements, but many of them are not governed by what is usually thought as contract law. Some agreements, such as domestic arrangements, are not governed by law at all.
What is a contract? In Anglo-American legal systems defines contract as a promises or set of promises for the breach of which the law gives a remedy or the performance of which the law recognizes in some way as a duty. However, not all promises give rise to contracts. For instance, if you agreed to keep the house tidy while your parents are away on holiday you would not expect to find yourself in the court of law being sued for the breach of contract if you failed to do so. So, what kind of agreements does the law recognize as creating enforceable rights and duties? To answer this, we need to look in the rules of each legal system, which provide their own specific definitions of the term contract and its elements. For instance, the French civil code defines contract in article 1101 as an agreement to establish, vary, and extinguish rights and obligations of the parties. When we come to the Ethiopian legal system, we find the definition of contracts (enforceable agreements) under Article 1675 of the Ethiopian Civil Code. As such contract is defined as;
‘’An agreement whereby two or more persons as between themselves create, vary or extinguish obligation of proprietary nature’’.
This definitional article plus Article 1678 on elements of contract tell as in general the type of agreements enforceable by the law of contract in Ethiopian legal system. In the next chapters, you will study the details.
Purpose of the contract law
Contract law is primarily concerned with supporting institutions of exchange, which is an enormous part of our life carried on the basis of that are in some sense termed as agreement. Contract law has many purposes but the central one is to support and control the millions of agreements that collectively make up the market economy, and hence operates in the context of dispute resolution mechanism. Besides it empowers the parties to make agreements that the law will enforce. It also enables parties to the contract to make exchanges that might otherwise carry too great risk whether of disruption by some contingencies or default by the other party. Accordingly, contract law in this respect is the most important which creates smooth functioning of business transaction by creating certainty, predictability, and enforceability.
In this context, it is also important to note the different approaches to contract law determine its role. In the nineteenth century, at least in common law legal systems, the courts seemed to place great emphasis on freedom of contract. During this period the courts tended to reduce the numbers of rules controlling contract power. They see the role of contract law as enforcing the agreement of the parties. There are still writers who suggest that the law should enforce any agreement which was ‘freely made’ between the parties provided it has no adverse effect on others. These “libertarians” see the individual as the best judge of his or her own interest and consider that what was freely agreed is by definition, fair. Any attempt to use contract law to influence substantive outcomes (e.g. to try to produce a fairer distribution of wealth in society, or even to maintain the previous distribution) is both illegitimate and misguided.
Others take a less extreme position. They agree that individuals should be free to pursue their own self-interest but they recognize that in some cases ‘the market’ may not operate efficiently. For example, in cases where there is some kind of monopoly or where one party does not fully understand the contract, the law may need to intervene. Many such writers would say the contract law, whether we like it or not, does affect the distribution of wealth in society and that this should be recognized. A few writers go further and argue that it is no longer adequate to describe the law of contract as primarily concerned with supporting voluntary exchange in the market and correcting occasional abuses or market failures. In their view another transformation has taken place and the modern law’s prime concern is with controlling domination and promoting fair exchange and co-operation. When you deal Ethiopian law of contract, you need to assess which approach is adopted in the Ethiopian legal system.
Scope of Contract Law
The scope of contract law varies from country to country and from legal system to legal systems depending on the types of obligations they govern. Unlike non- contractual obligations in which a person undertakes an obligation not to wrong another by conduct that the law of tort establishes as wrongful, contract law governs contractual obligations which arises from agreements made between two or more persons which puts the promisor under the obligation to perform his or her promises under the sanction of an action against him for breach of the contract.
A contractual obligation implies the existence of an ‘obligor’-the person who is legally under the obligation and the ‘obligee’ for whose benefit the obligation exists. This feature of contract distinguishes contract law from criminal law obligations.
Moreover, contract law may have a general or special application depending on the nature and origin of contractual undertakings at a given time. Therefore, based on the scope of application of contract law contract laws may be dissected in to two areas of applicability complementing each other. For instance, article 1676(1) of the Ethiopian civil code stipulated the application or scope of general contract to apply to contracts regardless of the nature thereof and the parties thereto. Thus, the general rules of contract law apply to all contracts. However, the provision also recognizes that special provisions, as laid down in Book V of the Civil Code and the Commercial Code, may be applicable to certain contracts. The law also stipulates that the relevant provision of the Civil Code, Book IV title XII, shall apply to obligations notwithstanding that they do not arise out of contract. Accordingly, contract law may be applicable to extra-contractual obligations, unlawful enrichment obligation and so on. However, the scope of application of this law does not affect the special provisions applicable to certain obligations by reason of their origin or nature (Art. 1677(2)).
- Details
- Category: Contract Law
- Hits: 28292
The conceptual foundation of obligation traces as far back to ancient Roman law which defines obligation as a means of an undertaking or legally binding relationships where one party promises the other party to perform some acts or to do something. Ancient well-known Roman lawyers defined obligations based on their personal opinion, which as a result has developed the concept of obligation.
Year Gay, a Roman jurist, defines obligation as ‘a means of personal claim brought against another in order to force him before us to give us so as to we are able to enforce our rights. Gay also classifies obligation in terms of contract, quasi-contract, delict, and quasi-delcit
Pavel year also understood obligation as an undertaking not by Roman citizens to perform some acts or to do or to give or to render rights to non-roman citizens regarding to give, to do, or to render some rights to roman citizens.
The concept of obligation by both classical legal scholars was unilateral in character and discriminatory in nature since it imposes obligation to do, to give or to render rights only on non-roman citizens not the Romans.
However, the institute of Justinian defines obligation as a legally binding relations when Roman citizens undertake to perform certain acts or to do something in accordance with the Roman law.
Obligation defined in the institute of Justinian, differed from the obligations defined in the classical Roman jurists in that the institute defines obligation in the aspect that Roman citizens to carry out.
In general the concept of obligation can clearly be expressed as;
a) Obligation to give or not to give
b) Obligation to do or not to do
c) Obligation to render rights to others to do something.
Definition of Obligations
Black’s law dictionary defines obligation as ‘a legal duty or moral duty to do or not to do something’. Common-law scholars such as Fredrick Pollock defines obligation in its popular sense as merely synonym for ‘duty’. In its legal sense derived from roman laws ‘an obligation is the bond of legal necessity or vinculum juris which binds together two or more determinate individuals’.
John Salmond (year) defined obligation in its more general acceptation as ‘something the law or morals command a person to do a command that is made effective by the imposition of sanction if a person failed to comply such a command’
In the modern legal systems and currently existing legal materials, there is no exact or single whole definition of obligation. However, some scholars define it based on their own legal system For instance French judges define the term obligation as a legally binding relations to another party is obliged to give or to do or not to do something.
Likewise the Ethiopian civil code, in the book IV of the code uses the term obligations without defining what it means. However, like French judges who define obligations indirectly from article 1101 of the French civil code of the term contract as an agreement whereby two or more persons as between themselves create, vary or extinguish obligations of proprietary nature.
Sources of obligations
According to Gay, Roman jurist, the fundamental source of obligation can be classified into two:
a) Contract
b) Beyond the contract
Those obligations, which arises beyond the contract, are divided into unjust enrichment (quasi-contract), unlawful acts (delict) and causing physical injure to the person or causing damage to property of person (quasi-delict).
In modern time, the laws of different countries clearly express the sources of obligation. For instance, French civil code classifies the source of obligation as;
i) Obligation that arises from contract
ii) Obligations that arise beyond the contract
iii) Obligation that arises from the unlawful acts
iv) Obligations that arises from the causing of physical injure or causing material damage
vi) Obligations arising from law
In Ethiopian legal system, there are no clearly stated classifications of sources of obligations. But Art.1675 of Ethiopian civil code generally expresses obligations as arising from contractual agreements.
However, the close readings of the provisions of the civil code show that there are other sources of obligations-like those arising from non-contractual relationships (from Art.2027-2178), obligations arising from unlawful acts or obligation that arises from the causing of physical injure or obligation arising from the causing of material damage (fromArt.2027-2161) and finally, obligations arising from unjust enrichment (from Art.2162-2178).
In so far as an obligation arising from the law is concerned, it happens in situations when law imposes obligations on persons to give or not to give, to do or not to do some acts recognized in almost all-legal systems.
Obligation arising from the law is a unilateral obligation imposed on citizens or contracting parties without their consent. It includes among other things
- Obligation to pay income taxes
- Obligation to render military services
- Obligations of creditors
- Obligation of debtors
- Obligations of families to their children, etc.
Types of Obligations
Obligations can be classified based on the nature of activities, and the number of parties legally bound by the obligation. Accordingly, they can be classified into:
1) Divisible obligation
This is one whereby a party undertakes to perform its obligations by dividing into parties. For instance, if A and B owed C 1,000 BIRR such parties to the obligation perform or discharge the obligations by paying half (part) of the debt to C, which is 500 each.
2) Indivisible obligations
In this type of obligation, the performance of the obligation undertaken cannot be divided into parts. Hence, in this type of obligation partial performance is impossible given the conditions and circumstances of its formation, which does not allow the performance of obligation by dividing into parts.
3) Positive obligation
This is a situation where a person’s obligation is to do or to give some thing to another. It requires an action from the debtor.
4) Negative obligation.
This is a situation where a person’s obligation does not to do some thing or it refrains from doing some thing. Such obligations are also called obligations not to do.
Example, company A may agree with company B in which company A under takes an bligation not to produce or sell certain goods in the same market.
Based on the number of parties legally bound, obligations can be classified into unilateral, bilateral, and multilateral obligations.
a) Unilateral obligation arises from contract in which two parties are participate. However, only one of the parties is legally bound by the contract for the benefit of the other contracting party. Example, donations
b) Bilateral obligation arises from a contract entered into by two parties in which these contracting parties are bound legally to each other on equal terms. Accordingly, there are two promisors and two promises.
c) Multilateral obligation. This is a case where more than two persons undertake to perform an obligation. Such obligations can be classified into three:
1) Simple joint obligation
2) Joint obligations
3) Several and joint obligations
1) Simple joint obligation
In this type’s obligation, parties who are bound by such obligation are not jointly liable for the total debts, but each debtor is liable for its own share with the exception of Art.1917 of the Ethiopian civil code
2) Joint obligations
It arises from the contractual obligation in which more than two parties participate and debtors are jointly liable for the debt secured as a result of the obligation entered into with the creditor or creditors.
3) Several and joint obligations
In this kinds obligations the co-debtors shall be jointly and severally liable unlike joint obligation where the debtors are jointly obliged to undertake a given obligation, in the several and joint obligation, the creditor may require all the debtors or one of them to discharge the obligation in whole or in part.